>> From the Library of Congress in Washington D.C. >> Mary-Jane Deeb: Good afternoon everybody. And welcome, welcome to the, to our reading room the African and Middle Eastern Reading Room. I'm Mary-Jane Deeb, Chief of the Division and I'm delighted you could be here with us. And for this special talk with Professor Stephen King, at Georgetown University. Before I start we have, we want to point out to you that this program is taking place in the context of the Library of Congress's collection; so it is part, in a way part of the collection. It's going to become part of the archives of the collections. And all our programs in this division, other divisions are complement the collections that we hold. So, this division is responsible for 78 countries around the world, in Africa, the Middle East, Southern Asia and the caucus's. And we collect, we recommend, we collect, we store collections which come to us from our offices in Cairo in Nairobi, in Islamabad. Those three offices actually send us materials. They purchase the materials, they catalog those materials and they send them to us and we keep them in the stacks, closed stacks right here and then we show them to researchers. This is one part of our activities. The other part of course, is to because we are the public face of the Library, is to interact with the researchers and the patrons, to serve them. We are public servants, so we serve them. The collections, we're experts in our fields and this division has 21 experts. And we know the languages, the cultures, the sources that we have. And we invite experts who are outside of this institution to come and to share with us their research work, their thoughts on the new trends in the fields of African and Middle Eastern studies. We are in a way, a focus of interaction between patrons and between those who serve the collections. We are also, we show films. We have displays and exhibits and we invite scholars to bring their students if they can, to the library as well. We've moved from up to the 18 year old, we're going down to 15 and 16 year old. Younger than that, they should be accompanied by their parents. But, anyway I want to put today's lecture in quick focus in terms of the Library's collection on Tunisia. Some of you have already seen them. Now this doesn't work quite that way. I was hoping it would, but anyway. Okay. So this is the room where you're in. This is where we serve you with the collections. We have reference sources for the journalists. We also have works on archaeology. We have ancient manuscripts, we have old maps, those are found in various parts of the library. We have prints and photographs on Tunisia, which includes the ones you've seen and these. We have collections of vintage posters. We have travel books on Tunisia, World War II maps, we have a veterans project that includes veterans speaking about their times in Tunisia. We have papers such as the Roosevelt papers, manuscripts in the manuscript division. Here is Stephen Kings book and members of others who are there as well. We have newspapers and journals. We have a website of archives taken from Tunisia at the when it was, during the Industrial Revolution; so these are very specialized, we have vigils. The law library has materials as well on laws. We have literary works, language dictionaries and materials on linguistics, arts and crafts, even cook books. And definitely we have programs such as this one and this is an example of a program that took place on Tunisia. Now, we also partner with associations that work on the countries and regions of our interest. And today's program is co-sponsored. We work together with the American Tunisian Association. And many people today in the -- in this room are members of the American Tunisian Association. I'm saying this because we're being webcast. And the webcast appeared on the libraries webpage, eventually, it takes a little time. We move slowly but surely. But eventually you will be able to see this program, and this program can be seen in every part of the world. And we realized through our social media that other people actually do watch our programs, and do check in. Angie Hall who is in our division has put together a Facebook page as well as organized blogs. Not only for this division, but for all the areas studies. And I know she has distributed some forms to you, so we'd be happy if you like us on Facebook and on the blogs, if you subscribe to it, it's free. Just click and subscribe. And if you become our friend because if you do then you'll be aware of all the programs that we're getting because part of the things we put up is a calendar of our events. And the calendar of our events is an open invitation for you all to come and attend our many programs. So again, thank you for coming and now I would like to introduce our speaker today. After this long introduction of mine, but anyway, Stephen King is Associate Professor of politics in the Department of Government at Georgetown University. He received a BA with honors in English and an MA in African Politics from the University of Florida. And he received an MA in Politics in Near Eastern Studies from Princeton University where he also got his Doctorate in Politics. Professor King is a comparativist who has focus in his work on the Middle East and North Africa. He is the Author of Liberalization Against Democracy: The Local Politics of Economic Reform in Tunisia published by Indiana University Press in 2003. And the New Authoritarianism in the Middle East and North Africa, also published by Indiana University Press in 2010. He teaches Comparative Politics, the politics of North Africa, Authoritarianism and comparative perspective, the Middle East in Comparative Perspective, and politics of the Third World. After obtaining his PhD in Politics from Princeton he taught at the university level in various institutions and including Georgetown University before he became associate professor. He also taught in Morocco, completed a full grad stint in Tunisia, was a visiting scholar at Woodrow Wilson center for international center for scholars. And in addition to his two books mentioned above, he has written numerous articles and book chapters on development in the Middle East and North Africa. His theoretical concerns, the theoretical concerns of his research, the focus on the links between economic liberalization and political change. And he has challenged many of the assumptions that we hold. So, without any further ado let me introduce Professor King. [ Applause ] >> Stephen J. King: Well thank you Mary-Jane for inviting me and happy to see the audience here and the broader world on this web case. Mary-Jane can you remind me on the final title we decided on for this topic? >> Mary-Jane Deeb: It was the challenge -- >> Stephen J. King: Well the economic transition that Tunisia, sorry. [ Inaudible ] >> Stephen J. King: The economic transition that Tunisia's democratic transition deserves. As you can tell from the introduction I'm interested in Tunisia and I've spent some time there. Now my general research interests in layman's terms is that I'm interested in the politics of the switch from Arab Socialism or from Socialism to Capitalism. And by politics I mean in the way that Harold Ashwell defined it. Who gets what, when and how? And the switch from Arab Socialism to Capitalism within the literature is usually grouped under the political economy of development. And largely begins with the economic development strategies of these countries. And coming to most of the developing world, they're world, Tunisia included made a transition from Arab Socialism, which meant the practice stayed on enterprises, land reform, a new social contract to provide basic food and fuel and housing, education. The new social contract after independence for development. The second strategy is the strategy that's been implemented over the last two to three decades. It's usually called the Washington Consensus. And clearly it's a switch to policies that are based on market reforms, market forces, privatization, capitalism broadly said and this Washington Consensus set of policies have been advocated by the World Bank and IMF for, since about the 80's I suppose. And connected to the loans that they provide developing countries there are these recommendations to implement those Washington Consensus. The Washington Consensus, it has 10 policies. And I won't talk about them all, but the advice is in two areas. One is in stabilization of the economy and for stabilization of the economy they advise that countries slow down inflation through fiscal discipline and improving the financial position of the state. Now the one policy I want to focus on is budget cuts to improve the financial position of the state. Arab Socialism or that phase of the development strategies included outlays by the state to pay for the subsidies and fuel and education and so forth. So the advice is to cut those in -- >> Stephen J. King: And engage in fiscal discipline. People talk about austerity policies, recessionary, austerity policies. And when our countries began doing these there was a reaction in the countries, the cuts in subsidies were politically explosive or bread riots across the region. I can't remember what year they occurred in Tunisia. But they occurred in Morocco, Tunisia, across North Africa and much of the Arab world, these riots against the subsidy cuts. The other group of policies are under the label of structural adjustment. And the ones I want to focus on are free trade, free in prices, privatization of state on enterprises in land. Okay. And I want to highlight under privatization, as privatization of state on enterprises and also privatization of land. In the World Bank and IMF argue that the privatization should benefit small land holders, land owners. And why do they say that? There's a belief that small farm size, family owned farms especially they limit the supervision costs of managing wage, labor and the -- and enforcing effort. You can get more effort. You don't have to supervise your family that work hard. And generally the small farms tend to be the most productive. Large land owners can be absentee or prestige land owners and not use the land productively. There's a danger of over production in large farms and within the Washington Consensus this privatization of land, this land reform is usually suggested as a counter to the charge that structural adjustment, that the Washington Consensus helped, hurts the poor. They argued that. The poor will be helped with the land privatization to the small family farms. So, going to Tunisia and Tebourba; I'm interested in these issues because of this switch to the Washington Consensus and the politics of that switch. And Tunisia gave me an opportunity to do research about this and I decided that there's less research on the local level, on land privatization. And I won't stay in the capital. I want to look at state on enterprises. I'll look at the local level and so I found a research site Tebourba, those of you know Tunisia. And the timing was the 1990's when the end stages of Arab Socialism in Tunisia were coming about. They were privatizing the agricultural cooperatives put in place by Ben Salah. So, I got a chance to be there on the ground while they were doing that. So, I was there for a year and they were going through this process and so, to research the politics as who gets what, when, where and how I mean the Washington Consensus, the expectation is that well, family farms, small land owners, the poor will benefit -- the society will benefit because there will be greater productivity and efficiency. Farming will be -- as we move into a more market economy resources will be allocated more efficiently, taking the state out of the economy, will stop corruption and all of these benefits. So I go and their privatizing these farms and I went to four or five villages around there. And the first step when I got there was okay, I needed to know land tenure as it stands now and what the plans are for this privatization. So, I go to the local officials there and I ask if I can see land tenure information, who owns what. That one question ended my research. >> The delegate said "Tomorrow you go see the governor". And they revoked -- I was on a Fulbright and they revoked my research clearance. So, I went back to Tunis and it was -- it took about six weeks to get it back. And we got it back because someone within the, I think because someone working for Fulbright, a Tunisian working for Fulbright used his connections to get my research clearance back. Okay, so I go and I know that people worried about when the authorities were worried about land tenure information. And I eventually got it in various ways. I think the biggest was on some wall in a local official's office and he stepped out and I was writing everything down as much as I could. But anyway gradually I got an idea and the overall story was the land reform was upward. It went to large land owners. It went to the best connected local people politically. And so I designed the research -- I made a research design where I would interview people from different large land owners, small, medium, local officials; I was interviewing everyone about these issues. And I'd like to read a few of the passages from these interviews with these different economic categories in Tebourba while they were undergoing land reform. >> Okay this was a poor peasant. "The workers have become beggars. The sun shines on everyone. Normally the state looks after us all. Why give the land to the rich? They already have land. If you give them more, they will no longer think of the poor. What are they going to do with more? Buy another car. It's no good. You find people with 1,000 1,000 hick cars while others won't even have one hick car. The poor one at land, some farmers before got land and they're doing well. But if you have connections that's the only way you can get land. Those who are fired like me, we go to the administration asking for work and tell them "You fired us, so give me something to buy bread", nothing happens". Another one. "The poor will always stay poor around here. The poor like rain and grass for the animals. The rich one allowed them to graze on their land, before you could. Now you can't". "If there's assistance from the state, [Inaudible] will give 50% of it to the people and the rest he'll keep for himself and his friends". It goes on like this in addition to the anger at how the land was privatized. There was anger about the state pulling out in about land owners no longer contributing as much as they did before to a moral economy. They're giving the land and the moral economy in that area was about -- for the poorest getting enough resources to last through the year, and part of the way they got it was the gifts of the rich during Islamic holidays in that harvest time. And that was part of how they managed their budget. So there was some pressure trying to encourage them to do it, criticizing them for not doing it. And the wealthy that I talked to said "Yeah, now we don't do that anymore", we're a modern society. The state does that; we don't have to do that. So there was that tension of should they help the poor in this time when they're getting great benefits from the state. And through my interviews with the wealthier and with the government people I got the impression that the state was pushing these land owners to do more, give more in terms of this, at the Islamic holidays during harvest and it was like an offset for, okay we give you this land, now you have to do this. And that's how they privatized the land from the Ben Salah cooperatives. So what did I take from that? I took a few things; obviously the land reform was upwards. That meant crucially that what's behind the banner of they switched the capitalism and market forces and privatization and the Washington consensuses different. What's behind that banner? What's behind that banner was the powerful taking advantage of privatization. Behind that banner somewhat pushing producers toward an old moral economy instead of the rational act or productive people that the policies are supposed to trigger, it's supposed to support. Okay, So that was my dissertation and first book went along those lines. Later when I did research, the research area was about regime change. And literature this is you know 10 years ago I suppose when I started this. The big debate, this is pre-Arab Spring, was about Authoritarian persistence, and for regional scholars. I was looking at that and we were trying to explain why this persistence of authoritarianism in our region, what can be done to democratize the region? Research along those lines and my thought was this, it doesn't look like we're moving towards democratization, but there's a lot of change. Remembering what happened in Tunisia, in Tebourba. I was thinking there are great changes in economic policies, asset distribution, and that's within authoritarianism. So I, my next research was about change within authoritarianism. And so analytical framework developed was to look at change, in regime change by looking at four areas. One or what are the policies? And the policies again, are privatization, free trade, land reform -- - right, land reform upward. What are the basic policies? What's the ruling coalition? What are the political institutional changes? And what are the changes in terms of legitimacy? And so basically if we're going from the Aram Socialism paradigm to this Capitalist paradigm the new policies or the Washington consensus politics, we talked about that one. The ruling coalition at the local level I figured out were large land owners. At the national level and what stayed on enterprise, I figured out doing the research that it was the same. The assets were going to the wealthiest and the best and politically connected, they became the new ruling coalition, Arab socialism is more of a populist coalition. This has become a ruling coalition for a favoring the wealthy. Institutional change, a facade of multi-party politics went along with this switch to capitalism. And finally with legitimacy you get some legitimacy from fake elections and the other piece is how much repression is necessary to make this regime change in these four areas? And so in that research I found a similar thing as I found in Tebourba, the most powerful -- getting great advantages from that change. They were taking these advantages and they were aided by a Washington consensus set of policies that said the economy will grow; you'll end corruption, all of these benefits for this switch. >> Is that what I found? No. What I found was more of a Crony Capitalist form of authoritarian rule is what emerged. And you know it's on the ground, what did you see? We saw ruling -- a small ruling click and patronage networks that were dominating the economy. They use security institutions in the police and the judiciary to maintain power within that, this small ruling click. And now that's what the young Tunisia looked basically at the Arab Republics Tunisia, Egypt, Algeria and Syria. And there's an economist who worked -- the Arab Human Development reports that were a group of Arab Economists working on that. And I got to know Nader Fergani and he was the head of that I believe. And I talked to him about it, what was going on in Tunisia and he said, "The same thing in Egypt". And this is the crux of our conversation about it. >> "Egypt's privatization and structural adjustment programs have led to a brand of chronic capitalism. The operative factors are very sinister cohabitation of power and capital. The structural adjustment program is helping to reconstruct a kind of society where a small number of people, where a small number of people on the line share of assets. Privatization in effect has meant replacing the government monopolies with private monopoly. The Middle Class has been shrinking while there's an enlargement of the super-rich. State owned enterprises have been sold to a minority of rich people. The record of private sector enterprises creating jobs is very poor. We are not reaping the benefits of an energetic bourgeoisie. What we have is a parasitical comprador class. The consequences will be no less than catastrophic. This society is a candidate for difficult period of intense violent social conflict and the kind of government we have will not do. A conversation took place around 2009, 2010 just before the Arab Spring. Okay so moving ahead to the Arab Spring and we know Tunisia has made wonderful progress in its transition to democracy, with some remaining challenges. But by far the best example and a lot of great progress. Part of what the Arab Spring was about not just democracy and human rights, dignity and socioeconomic justice and so the research I'm working on now; part of it is about the economic transition. The economic transitions that are going along with these transitions to or towards democracy. And I did some research and finally I found the vein of research from economists who know the region. And they were talking a lot about it's not just a democratic transition; it's an economic transition as well. And what would be the best economic transition for the Arab World. And -- instead of the Washington Consensus, this is their version of what's necessary. There are really five economic transitions that need to take place. One you need a developmental state that is capable of implementing an industrial policy, okay? It's improving the capacities of the state and giving it a role also in fostering industrialization Two, a productive private sector wean off corruption. Three, a vigorous social policy focused on the young. Four, improved economic relationships with the IFI's, the region and the world. Five inclusive socioeconomic policy making. Okay? And their reaction in general was this. After the Arab Spring and recognizing the socioeconomic causes of the Arab Spring. And we have to recall that Tunisia at the time was portrayed as the model for the Washington Consensus having the best results. In -- and we found out after the Arab Spring that some of the results warrant -- some of the data, information wasn't sound about Tunisia. It was probably more poverty than they were reporting. An employment was probably higher, regional inequality was great, those kinds of things. So this group of economists argued that economic reform strategy that Tunisia deserves takes advantage of the opportunities for economic growth provided by the global market, provided by global markets in a vigorous private sector while avoiding the simple minded application of market liberalization, privatization and a minimal state that led to crony capitalist forms of authoritarian rule. Okay? >> Now since it's been what, six years since the revolution? And how has Tunisia done in regards to these five areas? Well I mean the developmental state, increasing capacity, a work in progress. The productive private sector wean of corruption. There are a lot of complaints that the private sector is still corrupt. And there's been a loss of momentum even about trying to get back the money that was stolen during that period. And by the way we have some idea of who stole it in Tunisia. And a lot of it as you know, it's the extended family of Ben Ali. And the World Bank even had this accounting of corruption. By the end of 2010 some 220 firms connected to Ben Ali and his extended family were capturing an astounding 21% of all private sector profits annually in Tunisia. A small group of 114 people. Okay, so the efforts to recoup that money from Ben Ali and his family and the cronies related to them has stalled and as far as I can tell a lot of this is a work in progress obviously. As I think [Inaudible] in this government has suggest that we need to reconcile without continuing to seek that money; we need to move on with our private sector to an extent. I spend most of my days teaching, so I'm keeping day to day up on this -- it doesn't happen, but in the last year or so these things are coming out. On the vigorous social policy focused on the young, yes that's occurring and a lot of the money, the aid money that's going to Tunisia is probably going to various projects, social policy, helping with job training or various programs to help the young, that's occurring. The institutional development of inclusive socioeconomic policymaking. Social dialog impacts -- that's important because what would it do? It would provide an opportunity to obtain a more humane, collaborative and just capitalism. It would also help the rationality of economic policy because in those dialogues what can happen is that workers and business employers in the government can have the conversation about expectations. What can be done without ruining the economy and so that you collaborate on the challenges, you give the people who need it and who participate in the revolution to get it. Some concrete advances without them being overwhelming, all right? If you don't do it, what you end up getting is economic policy. It can be sabotaged by strikes going back and forth. Strikes, money is paid out. This is what was happening in Tunisia for a while. There was one example, one town some people; I can't remember what industry they were in. They were striking and the government answered their demands and then all the towns around asked for the same thing. So, that was not working. So, having a national dialogue about this to move towards a socioeconomic pact seems important. Tunisia in 2012 or I think 2012/2013 they've had a history of national dialogues and social packs that try Apartheid under Ben Ali with labor, Utica the economic association and the government. And they agreed to form committees I believe. It was something sort of basic, basic to explore this in 2012/2013. Then the instability, insecurity the assassinations happen in the -- and it went to the back burner. After the quartet does the national dialogue that resolves that impasse and gets the Constitution through and the success of that, the Nobel Prize and so forth led by the National Labor Federation. People were talking; well maybe we should do something concretely in the economic realm, that's just what we need. And then the last year or so this has been not he docket 2016, I think the -- I think they had it, but we don't know the results yet. It's been -- it hasn't gone on long enough. But they did meet and I think it was on the rubric of an employment dialogue, something more limited. But then it also was different in that political parties participated in civil society but -- so that's happening now. The last piece of advice for the economy that Tunisia deserves is back to the IFI's, the International Financial Institutions. They need a better relationship with Tunisia and you can tell from what I've been discussing what's happening in practice on the ground is different from the Washington Consensus that IMF and the World Bank are putting on paper. So the change in relationship we also start -- needs to also happen with IMF and the World Bank. They have to recognize elite capture; they have to involve civil society so that the policies aren't hijacked to the benefit of a small number, those kinds of things. Is that happening? It isn't. The 2016 was also an IMF agreement for a loan that went exactly back to the Washington Consensus, austerity, no real social policy and the simple application of privatization and free trade and so forth. So that was happening again and got a bad reaction, the [Inaudible] threatened to have a national strike. And there are some debate "Well maybe we should instead of unilaterally putting these policies in, we should open it up, collaboratively and democratically". So, at least they're discussing that and its -- and that's where I think we are. Thank you. [ Applause ] >> Mary-Jane Deeb: Thank you, thank you very much. And now the floor is open for questions and I'm going to take the first one and then I -- I wanted to ask you about the process. In the first stage it was changes in the agricultural land ownership. In the second stage it was austerity, more and Washington Consensus, those measures. So, in the third stage is the emphasis on creating new industries as you pointed out? And is there a market for those products? >> Stephen J. King: The -- the World Bank and IMF don't seem to be convinced that an industrial policy is necessary. It still doesn't seem to be part of the program; so we're getting the same thing, which by the way ended up de-industrializing. What the open up too soon or without production and de-industrialized industries in Tunisia and various places. And they're saying the same thing, they're repeating, there's no specific industrial policy. And the second part of your question was -- >> Mary-Jane Deeb: Would there be a market for -- [ Inaudible ] >> Stephen J. King: Well I mean to take advantage of the opportunities in global capitalism, they need you know, efficient products. If they're competitive, they are; if they're not, they're not. >> Mary-Jane Deeb: I think in their area they could be. >> Stephen J. King: That, I mean I think an economist would, who knows -- I'm more interested in the politics of it. I don't know the exact details of which companies that they should emphasize and where they are on that. I mean they had a manufacturing base and regionally they were known for progress in that direction. But, I don't know off hand the details of that. Yeah. [ Inaudible ] >> What is Tunisia's comparative trade? [ Inaudible ] >> They have this free trade agreement with Europe and the EU had it for some time. What has been the impact of that and does this work with consensus structure, does it work in a more liberalization direction of [Inaudible]? >> Stephen J. King: Yeah the -- when Tunisia was getting the high marks prior to the Arab Spring, I mean the reports were it was working. I mean, in olive oil and agricultural products were the main things. There was one paper on olive oil led growth for Tunisia. And so I mean the World Bank, they were getting 46 percentage growth rates during that five, six year period prior to the Arab Spring, which is good. So you know the numbers weren't all wrong. And -- but moving from that, that's a comparative -- I mean the part about comparative advantage, the East Asian examples where the most progress has happened. We talked about their products -- their products became competitive in about a generation, South Korea under park. So -- [ Inaudible ] >> Stephen J. King: I mean they had a development strategy that the World Bank and IMF don't consider, the East Asian Development Strategies. It's a different one. They've done the best, so it should be on the agenda as consideration, but that isn't -- because of the East Asian model they have an industrial policy. They have protectionism in order for these industries to get on their feet. But they have a bureaucracy that's different. I mean there would have to be great progress in improving the bureaucracies in Tunisia; so that they can play the kind of role in industrial policy that they play in East Asia. But I mean the point is, Bill's question is evidence seems to suggest a need for a dynamic comparative advantage. And that doesn't seem to be part of IMF and the World Bank. That you start with this olive oil like growth, but eventually you need to get to manufacturing. And you need a bigger role for the state in getting there than they've been willing to consider. >> It's an interesting anomaly, I mean -- [ Inaudible ] >> Tunisia moved from a government led oligarchy to a privately led oligarchy over time; still an oligarchy. And when of the recommendations is the break down, business classes [Inaudible]. [Inaudible] Which leaves the IMF to suggest that the way to do that is to liberalize [Inaudible] to get rid of the banking and customs and all the internal regulatory system which favors the [Inaudible]. You get rid of it, to literalize it entirely. They can't get that through [Inaudible]. They absolutely cannot. So how do you break down the Middle Class oligarchy, Upper Middle Class oligarchy if you will that's totally dependent on government subsidies who experience regulations on [Inaudible]. >> Stephen J. King: It's modified strategies, strategy of this group of economists do talk about that, about deregulation and making a business environment better for all, that's one of their open thrall, better and open. It's -- that's one of their recommendations that is to do that. How do you get it done? I mean there are best practices and they refer to involving the private sector, I'm thinking now more about the corruption part of it. The -- and no impunity for corruption. If you prosecute the people who have done it, deal with the safe havens abroad, where the money is stored, the World Bank and IMF using their leverage to take steps that will prevent elite capture. It's a work in progress, that's the directions that they outline. >> I guess what I'm saying is production goes further than just plan stealing; it goes to the rigging the economic system, regulatory system [Inaudible], that's one. >> Stephen J. King: Yeah. No, they say deregulate. I mean that's what the advice is to deregulate. Deregulation is a part of this modified economic reform strategy. [ Inaudible ] >> Stephan J. King: No, I accept the, I accept and I defer to the economists that the best we can do is this modified economic -- this modified market reform strategy that doesn't have [Inaudible] privatization, trade and other policies of the Washington Consensus. And so it still, it's not -- their strategy is for capitalism that is more compassionate, that works for more as a shared growth kind of capitalism. It's an inclusive Democratic change to capitalism. And it's dynamic look at capitalism where you change from what you're doing within the capitalist economy now to something that gets more benefits over time. But it's still within -- it's still capitalist. Yeah. [ Inaudible ] >> Deregulation, privatization, so-called free trade which is a misnomer [Inaudible] trade agreements there are some areas that are [Inaudible] protection aspects in terms of [Inaudible]. A prime example is prescription drugs and patent extensions and copyright extensions and the monopolies over those. [Inaudible] so it's not free trade, its managed trade and the way that's been applied with [Inaudible] is that they be international [Inaudible] and then local economy [Inaudible] with that kind of dynamic. So, what's happening with deregulation is that businesses -- some businesses are [Inaudible], others aren't. [ Inaudible ] >> Those are being dismantled under deregulation. Privatization has led also to the benefit of certain private [Inaudible], and that's within the power structure. So my question is whose got the power? How do you present Middle Class, Working Class. [Inaudible] The Middle Class [Inaudible] how do you build them up? How do you change the power structure, build an economy that benefits the mass of people and not just this global financial system and then [Inaudible]. That's a question for [Inaudible] too. >> Stephen J. King: Yes. >> The policies in the US [Inaudible] deregulation [Inaudible] with aiding and becoming [Inaudible]. >> Stephen J. King: In terms of -- >> How do you deal with that in terms of power, economic policy? >> Stephen J. King: Yeah I mean they usually, the National Labor Federation was powerful in Tunisia and the collaborative, the social dialogue, having the pack, getting people to make a pack that's bringing labor, the employers, government together to address these -- to have these conversations. That's -- and to come up with policies collaboratively that will help the Middle and Lower Class, and also you know, the broader economic issues that you're talking about. If we want it to be more shared, it has to be a more inclusive policy making. And Tunisia has scheduled that. They recognize that. And they're bringing people together. I mean this -- it's just within the last year or so that they had the pack and I haven't had a chance to read fully. I know that they're focused on employment and they were like 11 recommendations. But that's how accepting capitalism but also dealing with changing the power structures. And some of the economists, the Tunisian economists with this socioeconomic pack dialogue, they're more worried about labor than they're worried about business. Because politically labor is so strong. And the labor might have the power to demand enough that you don't solve the broader economic issues. But -- [ Inaudible ] >> I was wondering about what recent stressors there are on this privatization, this concentrated [Inaudible] is there kind of a resistance to what [Inaudible] are you getting pressures from migrants, stressors from external groups [Inaudible] and what are these doing to -- [ Inaudible ] Stephen J. King: The security issues in external groups that adds -- put socioeconomic dialogue impacts sort of the -- on the back burner. It's one of the things that can get in the way; that's certainly true. I mean Arab Spring we ended up not getting the changes of that -- the people, the economists they were writing. They were hoping that you can move to regional, more regional economic cooperation because North Africa it looks like we might get new Democratic governments. And you have a chance but we didn't get that, Libya is where it is now in this war. And so the, the regional piece seems stalled at this point. Mm-hmm. >> Can you talk about this sort of capitalistic model, socialistic model. Just wondering, has anyone tried to find out [Inaudible] in Tunisia, [Inaudible] one or the other; or is it just not on their radars? >> Stephen J. King: The, I mean, I think there's a general point that Islam's tend to favor capitalism and free markets, private enterprises. There's more hostility, socialism and the eastern block and atheism and profit, merchant and private properties is important. In the Tunisian context the -- the leftist parties and the national labor federation are -- they are enemies more or less, not enemies but they are in conflict with the Islamists. And so if anything more business orientated to an extent. They've tried to start their own labor federation, the Islamists and as reaction to too much power by the more left leaning national labor federation. >> Mary-Jean Dobb: We have to stop now but I want to thank the speaker for a wonderful presentation and to thank you all for coming. >> This has been a presentation of the Library of Congress. Visit us at loc.gov.